; ECON 501
Documents
Resources
Learning Center
Upload
Plans & pricing Sign in
Sign Out
Your Federal Quarterly Tax Payments are due April 15th Get Help Now >>

ECON 501

VIEWS: 17 PAGES: 20

  • pg 1
									                                                   Updated: 21 March, 2007




             MICRO ECONOMICS
                (ECON 601)

                         Lecture 3

Topics to be covered:
a. General Competitive Equilibrium
b. Edgeworth Box Diagram
c. Efficient Allocations
d. Production Possibility Frontier
e. Rate of Product Transformation
f. Determination of Equilibrium Prices
g. Real Cost Reduction
h. General Equilibrium Modelling
i. The Corn Laws Debate
j. Existence of General Equilibrium Prices
k. Walrasian Solution
l. Walras Law
m. Definition of Economic Efficiency
n. Efficiency in Production
o. Efficient Choice of Inputs for a Single Firm
p. Efficient Allocation of Resources among Firms
r. Efficient Choice of Output by Firms
s. Theory of Comparative Advantage
                                             ECON 601
                                             Nicholson Chapter 12


General Competitive Equilibrium

Partial Equilibrium Analysis


                                    Px
                                                                          S



                                    P2
                                    P1
                                                                                   D1
                                                                     D0




                                         O        Q1      Q2                            QX


Initial Price Quantity (P1, Q1)


If something causes the demand for X to increase, then a new equilibrium is reached at (P2, Q2).

However for the quantity supplied to increase the factors of production that produce X must
come from somewhere else.



                               PY                               S1
                                                                              S0

                                  P Y2
                                  P Y1


                                                                               D



                                         O         Q Y2       Q Y1                      QY


The resources that produced greater supply of X are equal to the resources released from Y when
production fell from QY1 to QY2.

I Law of One Price: A homogeneous good trades at the same price no matter who buys it or
which firm sells it.




                                                          1
II Assumptions about Perfect Competition:

   -               Large number of buyers of each good. Each person takes all prices as given, maximizes
                   utility subject to a budget constraint.
   -               Large number of firms producing each good. Firms maximize profits- all prices, both
                   output and input prices, are given to each firm.

III General Equilibrium via Edgeworth Box Diagram

Assumptions:
1.   All individuals have same preferences
2.   Two goods X & Y
3.   Two factors of production K & L
4.   Fixed amounts of K & L.
                          Labor used in X                                   Labor used in Y
                                                                                              OY



                                                                                               Capital
       Total Capital




                                                                                               used in Y




                                                                        A                      Capital
                                                                                               used in X

              OX                                                 Total Labor
A is any production point that uses up all the factors.

Efficient Allocations in Production

                                                                                                   OY




                                                                        P4               X4
                       Total Capital




                                                            P3                      Y1
                                                                               X3
                                                 P2                   X2
                                                                   A Y
                                                                      2
                                                       Y3
                                       P1             X1
                                            Y4
                             OX                                       Total Labor


                                                            2
A is not an efficient point (X2, Y2) at P2 can produce same X2 but produce more Y3 at P3 can
produce same Y2 but at same time produce more X3.

The locus of the points P1, P2, P3, P4 are efficient because that is where the isoquants for
production of X and production of Y are just tangent with each other. No more of one good can
be produced without less of the other one of being produced.

This is referred to as the “Contract Curve”. Along this curve the (Rate of Technical Substitution)
RTSXKL = RTSYKL.

If one plots these points in X, Y, space they give us the production possibility curve.



                              QY

                              Y4
                                                The negative value of the slope of the
                                                tangent to the production possibilities
                                                frontier is the rate of product
              Quantity of Y




                              Y3                transformation

                              Y2

                              Y1




                                   X1      X2     X3 X4     QX            Quantity of X


Rate of Product Transformation RPT (of X for Y) = – slope of production possibilities frontier
                                                    dY
                                               =       (along OXOY)
                                                    dX

The RPT records how X can be technically traded for Y while continuing to keep the available
productive inputs efficiently employed.

The “normal” production probabilities frontier exhibits an increasing RPT




                                                 3
                     QY
                                        RPT is small  Y
                                                       X




                                                       RPT is large  Y
                                                                      X




                                                                     QX


To show that, RPT =  dY = MC X
                       dX     MC Y
Suppose total cost function to society = C (X, Y)

          dC = C dX + C dY = 0
             X       Y
        C dX = – C dY
         X        Y

For movement along production function,
              dY
      RPT=       (along OXOY)= C / C = MC X
              dX                  X  Y  MC Y


Why should RPT rise if QY and QX
      i.e. why RPT as QX

1.     Diminishing returns to scale
       –       What happens if constant returns to scale
2.     Specialized inputs
       –       Specific factor
3.     Differing Factor Intensites in Production of X and Y.
       –       Most general reason why the rate of RPT increases as more of X is produced.

Production possibility frontier will be concave if goods X & Y use inputs in different proportions.




                                                4
                                                                                                        OZ

                                                              B
                                                                                 P4
                                                                                                      W4
          Capital



                                                                           P3               Z1
                                                                                       W3

                                               P2                               Z2

                                                             Z3    W2
                            P1
                                                    W1
             OW                  Z4
                                                                        Labor

       W is relatively labor intensive
       Z is relatively capital intensive
       B is not as efficient as P3

Production possibilities frontier shows the economic concept of opportunity cost. Society can not
have more of X unless it gives up some of Y. Measured by RPT of X for Y.

Determination of Equilibrium Prices

- Introduce indifference curve map of society U1, U2

                                      U1
                                                U2
                    QY

                                           A
                    Y0

                                                         C                                       PX
                    Y*                                                          Slope = –
                                                                   B                             PY
                    Y1


                                                                                                      PX *
                                                                                     Slope = –
                                                                                                      PY *



                                           X0       X*            X1                        QX




                                                         5
                                                    *
                                               Px › Px
                                                    *
                                               PY       <PY

                                                    *     *
                                               > Px / P
                                               Px / PY Y
With PX and PY, firms gain maximum profits at A by producing at Y0,X0

Consumers will maximize utility at B with (X1,Y1)

       Excess demand for X = (X1 – X0)
       Excess supply of Y = (Y0 – Y1)

Hence PX, PY
      At C (Y*, X*), RPT = MRS




Suppose tastes change so that X becomes more attractive

                             – PX   0                     – PX      1

                                 PY0                              PY1
                  QY


                  Y0

                  Y1                                                           u00

                                                                              u11
                                                                        u01

                                                    X0            X1                 QX

             PX
In this case      from PX   0   to PX    1   and the quantity of goods produced and sold will move from
             PY         PY
                         0
                                        PY1
(Y0, X0) to (Y1, X1).

Effect of Technical Progress in Production of X (Real Cost Reduction)




                                                              6
                     Y


                  Y2

                  Y1                                                    u1
                                                                   u0


                                                     X1   X2                 X

                                          for sure X2 > X1

     Y2 may be <> Y1 depending on the relative strength of income and substitution effects.

Example: Comparative Statics in General Equilibrium Model

Suppose production function of both goods characterized by DRS as
x  l x .5 and y  l y .5
      0              0

PPF is given as x 2  y 2  100 and by taking total differential of this function and find
RPT as
2 xdx  2 ydy  0
              MC x  dy 2 x x
RPTxfory                 
              MC y   dx   2y y
For consume side, consumer preferences are given as utility function
U ( x, y)  x0.5 0.5
                 y
By setting the Lagrangian expression we can obtain Marginal Rate of Substitution x for y as
L  x 0.5 y 0.5   ( I  Px x  Py y )
                     L
               MU x x 0.5 x 0.5 y 0.5  Px y Px
MRS xfory                                  
               MU y L 0.5 x 0.5 y 0.5  Py x Py
                     y

General Equilibrium Requires                        x              y P
                                    RPT xfory          MRS xfory   x  1
                                                     y              x Py
Therefore, x = y and we can calculate values for x and y by using the PPF

                 x 2  y 2  100  x  x  100
                                    2   2

2 x 2  100
x     50
y      50

                                                 7
The Budget Constraint:
If w= hourly wage rate we have lx+ly=100 hrs and total labor income is 100w

Total, average, and marginal costs for production of x can be calculated as

C ( w, x)  wl x  wx 2
     C
AC     wx
     x
     C
MC      2 wx  Px  2w 50
     x
Therefore profit obtained from production of x will be

 x  ( Px  AC x ) x  (2wx  wx ) x  wx  50 w
                                          2


Similarly   50 w
           y

Hence, Total Income = Total Labor Income + Profits = 100w+2(50w) = 200w

Consumer spends 100w for good x and 100w for good y. This equilibrium can be shown

graphically as below

                    QY

                    100


                                         RPTx for y=MRSx for y=Px/Py
    Quantity of Y




                    50
                                E
                                                    U


                                                Px/Py




                          0                      100           Quantity of X
                                 50

This Equilibrium condition can be change due to two reasons:

   1. Change in supply (due to technological progress)

   2. Change in demand (due to change in preferences)



                                                8
Shift in Supply:

Suppose there is technical progress in production of x and production function for x becomes

x  2l x .5
       0


To obtain lx as a function of x

x2= 4 lx  lx= x2/4

therefore our new PPF would be

x2
    y 2  100
4

Total differential

                                               x
                                            ( )
                                     dy
  dx  2 ydy  0  RPTxfory
x                                              2  x
                                        
2                                    dx      2y   4y

In Equilibrium:

(supply)              x  P              (demand)           y Px
           RPT          x                        MRS     
                     4 y Py                                x Py

 x   y
   
4y x
x 2  4 y 2 and
    x2
y 
  2
    4
x2
    y 2  100
4

      2       2
So, x  x  100           2 x 2  400    x  2 50      and   y  50
      4     4

Therefore at Equilibrium               x  y P    1
                              RPT         x 
                                      4 y x Py 2

Due to technical progress relative prices of good x and y decreased and consumption of good x

increased (doubled).


                                                   9
For good y, negative substitution effect and positive income effect offset each other and no

change in quantity and price of good y.

On the other hand, due to technological progress in x production total utility derived increased


from U ( x, y )  x              ( 50 ) 0.5 ( 50 ) 0.5  50  7.07
                      0.5 0.5
                          y
      to U ( x, y )  (2 50 ) 0.5 ( 50 ) 0.5  2 50  100  10

This is also measurement of welfare change due to technological progress.

Shift in Demand:

Suppose demand for x significantly reduced and utility function becomes

U ( x, y)  x 0.1 y 0.9
By setting up Lagrangian expression subject to budget constraint we can find marginal rate of

substitution x for y as

               y Px
MRS xfory       
              9 x Py

So (supply)               x Px and (demand)              y Px
              RPT xfory                   MRS xfory     
                          y Py                          9 x Py
Equilibrium should satisfy x   y
                                  y 2  9 x 2 and y  3x
                           y 9x
If we substitute these into PPF
x 2  9 x 2  100       x  10           y  3 10

Therefore in equilibrium                               Px   10 1
                              RPTxfory  MRS xfory          
                                                       Py 3 10 3
Due to change in preferences relative prices of good x and y decreased. We cannot compare

welfare change here, because utility (preferences) changed.



General Equilibrium Modelling and Factor Prices

Corn Laws Debate in England 1829-45. High tariffs on grain: Question, should they be reduced?

Initially if tariffs prevented, all international trade equilibrium the economy would be at point E.
Impact of International trade – on production and returns to factors.



                                                 10
                  Y
                                                   0
                                                       u1
                                               u


     YA                                   A
                                                        E    B              Slope – (P*X/P*Y) if no grain tariffs
     YB


                                                                 Slope – (P’X/ P’Y) if tariffs on grain

                                              XA            XB                             X


With international trade and world prices of P*X and P*Y the country will produce at A with YA,
XA, but consumers will be able to consume at B, YB, XB. Hence, country will export (YA – YB) of
good Y for (XB – XA) of good X. A higher level of utility can be reached.

If Y is manufactured good and X is Corn then we would expect to find that land prices will fall
and wage rates rise after allowing international trade. Agriculture production is reduced and
because agriculture is land intensive, land prices will fall. As manufacturing will expand and
because it is labour intensive, wage rates will rise.

                                      Analyses using Edgeworth Box Diagram

                                                                                                         Mfg


                                                                      A
                                                                                      C1
                                                                      M2
                                                                                  0
                                                                               W /R0
        Capital




                       1
                      W /R   1       C2


                                 B



                             M1
       Corn                                                               Labor



Corn is capital intensive Mfg is Labor intensive. If one opens up to trade them, production moves
from A (more Corn; less Mfg) to B (less Corn; more Mfg) both production processes become
more capital intensive, hence, PK, PL. W1/R1 > W0R0


                                                            11
Existences of General Equilibrium Prices

Problem posed and solved by Leon Walras

Question: Does a set of non-negative prices exist that will equilibrate all the markets in an
economy?

Walrasian Solution

1.     Let goods be distributed someway in a society
       Si (i=1,…,n) Total supply of goods
       Pi (i=1,…,n) Price of goods ‘i’
       Demand for good ‘i’ Di (P1,....,Pn)

Demand is a function of all prices
     P = (P1,…,Pn)
     Di (P)
     Di (P*) = Si

Expressed as excess demand functions,
       EDi (P) = Di (P) – Si

In Equilibrium,
       EDi (P*) = Di (P*) – Si = 0

Assumptions:
1.   –       Assumed that demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero
2.   –       Demand functions are continuous
     –       Comes from theory of individual behavior

Walras Law

         n

         P ED ( P) = 0
        i 1
               i   i




Total value of excess demand is zero at any set of prices.

–      Given by the fixed budget constraint
–      Equilibrium conditions in n markets are not independent
–      Hence, we have only (n – 1) equations in (n – 1) unknowns.
–      Hence, what we need to determine for equilibrium is (n – 1) relative prices.

Proof: Two goods and two individuals I, II

For individual I.

       PADIA + PBDIB = PASIA + PBSIB
                      Budget constraint

       PA (DIA – SIA) + PB (DIB – SIB) = 0

                                                12
       PA (EDIA) + PB (EDIB) = 0
For individual II.
       Similarly, we have:
       PA (EDIIA) + PB (EDIIB) = 0

      PA (EDIA + EDIIA) + PB (EDIB + EDIIB) = PA (EDA) + PB (EDB) = 0

Walras proof of Existence of Equilibrium set of Prices (Equilibrium Relative Prices)

–      Problem is not solved easily because demand equations are not linear.
–      Prices must be non-negative.
–      In economics a negative price has no meaning.
_      The equilibrium is a simultaneous solution of prices and demands across all markets.



Example: General Equilibrium with Three Goods

The economy of Oz is composed only of three precious metals: 1- silver, 2- gold, and 3-
platinum. There are 10 (thousand) ounces of each metal available (S1=S2=S3=10). The demand
for gold is given by
                                p    p
                     D2  2 2  3  11
                                p1   p1
and for platinum by
                              p      p
                     D2   2  2 3  18
                              p1      p1


Notice that the demands for gold and platinum depend on the relative prices of the two goods and
that these demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero in all three prices. Notice also that
we have not written out the demand function for silver but, as we will show, it can be derived
from Walras’ law.
Equilibrium in the gold and platinum markets requires that demand equal supply in both markets
simultaneously: (D2=S2 and D3=S3)
To simplify calculations suppose
         p2
x 
         p1
and
          p3
y 
          p1
Then we can simply calculate values of x and y by using simultaneous equations methods (ie.
multiplying the second equation by (-2) and find corresponding value for y).

 2 x  y  11  10  2 x  y  1  0
 x  2 y  18  10   x  2 y  8  0
                              5 y  15  0




                                               13
Hence, we can obtain values for these relative prices as y=3 and x=2. In equilibrium, therefore,
gold will have a price twice that of silver, and platinum a price three times that of silver. The
price of platinum will be 1.5 times that of gold.

Walras’ law and the demand for silver: Because Walras’ law must hold in this economy we
know
 n
 pi .EDi ( P )  0
i 1

p1 ED1  p2 ED2  p3 ED3  0
p1 ED1   p2 ED2  p3 ED3

Solving this equation for the excess demands (by moving the fixed supplies to the left hand side)
and substituting into Walras’ law yields

           2         2
          p2        p3       p2   p
ED1  2    2
               2    2
                               8 3
          p1        p1       p1   p1

ED1  2 x 2  2 y 2  x  8 y (ED=D-S)

If we substitute values of x and y, we can see that the market for silver is also in equilibrium
(ED1=0) at the relative prices computed previously.



                             The Efficiency of Perfect Competition

Adam Smith put forth the idea that a competitive market would ensure that resources would find
their way to where they were most valued (the invisible hand). He provided the framework that
has given rise to modern welfare economics.

The fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics states that there is a close correspondence
between the efficient allocation of resources and the competitive pricing of these resources.


Definition of Economic Efficiency – Pareto Efficient Allocation

An allocation of resources is Pareto efficient if it is not possible (through further reallocations) to
make one person better off without making someone else worse off.


Efficiency in Production

Production Efficiency: An allocation of resources is efficient in production (or technically
efficient) if no further reallocation would permit more of one good to be produced without
necessarily reducing the output of some other good.

                                                  14
                 Y                         Production possibilities frontier.
                                 B


                           A                    C       A = technically inefficient
                                                        B & C = technically efficient




                                                                    X


Technically efficiency is a precondition for overall Pareto efficiency. However, technically
efficiency does not guarantee Pareto efficiency. The firm may be producing the wrong goods
efficiently.



Production efficiency: There are three aspects:
   1)     resource allocation within a single firm
   2)     allocation of production resources among firms
   3)     coordination of firms’ output decisions.

1.     Efficient choice of inputs for a single firm. We showed this previously with the
       Edgeworth Box diagram. In algebra, assume:
       a)      firm produces two outputs X, Y.
       b)     fixed amounts of inputs K , L .
       c)     production function for X = f (KX, LX).
       d)     assume full employment of both factors, hence, KY = K – KX and LY = L – LX
       e)     production function for Y
              Y = g (KY, LY)
                = g ( K – KX, L – LX)

              Technical efficiency requires that the output of X be maximized for any given
              level of Y eg. Y


              L =f (Kx, Lx) +  ( Y – g ( K – KX, L – LX))
               L
       1)          = fK + gk = 0
              K X


                                                15
                 L
       2)            = fL + gL = 0
                L X

       3)      ∂L/∂λ= Y – g ( K – KX, L – LX) = 0
                          fK  g
       From 1 and 2,         = K
                          fL   gL


       RTSX (K for L) = RTSY (K for L)


Efficient Allocation of Resources Among Firms
    – Necessary for overall efficiency. Resources should be allocated to those firms that can use
       them most efficiently.
   Suppose:
   a) Two firms produce X
   b) Production functions are f1 (K1, L1) and f2 (K2, L2)
   c) Total supplies of capital and labor are given by K and L




   Allocation problem is to maximize,
      X = f1 (K1, L1) + f2 (K2, L2)
   subject to constraints,
       K1 + K2 = K
     L1 + L2 = L
Maximization problem,
       X = f1 (K1, L1) + f2 ( K – K1, L – L1)

First order conditions,
        X   f   f   f   f
            = 1 + 2 = 1 - 2 =0
        K 1 K 1 K 1 K 1 K 2
        X  f  f   f f
           = 1 + 2 = 1 - 2 =0
        L1 L1 L1 L1 L2
                f 1   f 2
                     =
                K 1 K 2
                f 1  f
       and,          = 2
                L1 L2




                                                16
Rule:

The marginal physical product of any resource in the production of a particular good must be the
same no matter which firm produces the good.


Example Gains from Efficiently Allocating Labor
To examine the quantitative gains in output from allocating resources efficiently, suppose two
rice farms have production functions of the simple form

                                q  k 1 / 4l 3 / 4 ,
but one rice farm is more mechanized than the other. If capital for the first farm is given by k1=16
and for the second farm by k2 =625, we have
q1  (16)1 / 4 l1 / 4  2l1 / 4
                3         3

q 2  (625)1 / 4 l 2 / 4  5l 2 / 4
                   3          3


If the total labor supply is 100, an equal allocation of labor to these two farms will provide total
rice output of
Q  q1  q2  2(50) 3 / 4  5(50) 3 / 4  131.6
The efficient allocation is found by setting the marginal productivities equal:
          q1  3  1 / 4        q    15  
MPL 
  1
               l1        MPL  2   l 2 1 / 4
                               2
          l1  2                l 2  4 
Hence, for efficiency labor should be allocated so that
                                       4
1       2  15  1         5
              4  l1               l 2  0.0256l 2
 4
l1      3  4  l 2        2

Given the greater capitalization of farm 2, practically all of the available labor should be devoted
to it. With 100 units of labor, 97.4 units should be allocated to farm 2 with only 2.6 units to farm
1. In this case total output will be
Q  q1  q2  2(2.6)3 / 4  5(97.4)3 / 4  159.1
This represents a gain of more than 20 percent over the rice output obtained under the equal
allocation.
If capital were not fixed in this problem, marginal productivities of both capital and labor should
be equal for firm 1 and firm 2.


Efficient Choice of Output by Firms
Even though resources may be allocated efficiently both within the firm and between firms, it
must be the case that firms also must produce efficient combinations of outputs.



                                                   17
Output                                           Output
  of                RPT1A=1.5/1                                           RPT0=1/1
                                                   of
 Cars                                             Cars




                              RPT0A=2/1                                                  RPT1=1.5/1




          Firm A             Output of Trucks                  Firm B             Output of Trucks




Initially RPTA>RPTB = 1/1
Hence firm A should produce more cars and firm B should produce more trucks.
In this way RPTA0 will fall and RPTB0 will increase.
So that RPTA1 = RPTB1



Theory of Comparative Advantage
First proposed by David Ricardo: Countries should specialize in producing goods of which they
are relatively more efficient producers.

Suppose we now have two countries A & B,

   Output of Cars
    Y                  RPT1A=?                         Output of Cars
                                                         Y                 RPTB=1/1
   Y 1A

                                                        Y0B

   Y 0A
                                          RPT0A=2/1 Y1B                                         RPTB=?




                    X1A       X0A   Output of Trucks                        X0B         X1B    X
     Country A                                                Country B                       Output of Trucks



Both countries would gain if they produced more of the good for which they have a comparative
advantage. Country A should produce more of Y and country B should produce more of X.


                                                   18
Country A would be able to sell some of the Y produced to country A in exchange for purchase
of X. Both countries can be made better off. Initially country A can give up one unit of X and
produce 2 units of Y. For country B at its initial position it can be produced one more X for one
unit of Y. Hence, if A were to produce one unit less of X and hence produce two more units of Y,
it could trade with Country B one of those units of Y for one unit of X and it would be still better
off by one unit of Y. At the same time, country B would be left no worse off. World welfare
would be improved.
–       If a linear production function existed in both countries, to maximize world welfare each
        country should completely specialize in the production of one good. Not the case if
        concave production functions.




                                                19

								
To top